Wednesday, November 20, 2013

Excerpts from "Fooled by Randomness" by Nassim Taleb


Although he has not yet practiced the profession of high-sea piracy, he is now convinced that even that occupation would present more dull moments than that of the trader.

Trading forces someone to think hard; those who merely work hard generally lose their focus and intellectual energy. In addition, they end up drowning in randomness; work ethics, Nero believes, draw people to focus on noise rather than signal.

Nero believes that risk-conscious hard work and discipline can lead someone to achieve a comfortable life with a very high probability. Beyond that, it is all randomness: either by taking enormous (and unconscious) risks, or by being extraordinarily lucky. Mild success can be explainable by skills and labor. Wild success is attributable to variance.

His wife had rarely encountered repressed new wealth – the type of people who have felt the sting of indigence at some point in their lives and want to get even by exhibiting their wares. The only dark side of being a trader, Nero often says, is the sight of money being showered on unprepared people.

She felt as if she had been somewhat swamped in the competition of life. Somehow words and reason became ineffectual in front of an oversized diamond, a monstrous house and a sports car collection.

Nero tried to soothe his jealousy by investigating the rules of pecking order. Psychologists have shown that most people prefer to make $70000 when others around them are making $60000 than to make $80000 when others around them are making $90000.

Nero felt ashamed of his feelings of Schadenfreude, the joy humans can experience upon their rivals’ misfortunes. But in this case, Nero’s merriment did not come from the fact that John went back to his place in life, so much as it was from the fact that Nero’s methods, beliefs and track record had suddenly gained in credibility. Part of Nero’s elation also came from the fact that he felt proud of his sticking to his strategy for so long, in spite of the pressure to be the alpha male.

Lucky fools will act as they deserved the money. Their strings of successes will inject them with so much serotonin (or some similar substance) that they will even fool themselves about their ability to outperform markets (our hormonal system doesn’t know whether our successes depend on randomness).

There seems to be curious evidence of a link between leadership and a form of psychopathology (the sociopath) that encourages the non-blinking, self-confident, insensitive person to rally followers.

One can’t judge a performance in any given field by the results, but by the costs of the alternatives. Such substitute courses of events are called alternative histories. The public observes the external signs of wealth without even having a glimpse at the source. USD 10 million earned through Russian roulette doesn’t have the same value as USD 10 million earned through the diligent and artful practice of dentistry. They are the same, can buy the same goods, except that one’s dependence on randomness is greater than the other. To an accountant, though, they would be identical; to your next door neighbor too. Yet, deep down, I can’t help but consider them as qualitatively different. The notion of such alternative accounting has interesting intellectual extensions and lends itself to mathematical formulation (illustrative). Mathematics is just not a “numbers game”, it is a way of thinking.

For Leibniz God’s mind included infinity of possible worlds, of which he selected just one.

Reality is far more vicious than Russian roulette where the risk is visible to everyone. One doesn’t observe the barrel of reality.

It can be disturbing for many self-styled “bottom lone” oriented people to be questioned about the histories that didn’t take place rather than the ones that actually happened.

Heroes are heroes because they are heroic in behavior not because they won or lost.

As a derivative trader I noticed that people do not like to insure against something abstract; the risk that merits their attention is always something vivid.

Both risk detection and risk avoidance are not mediated in the “thinking” part of the brain but largely in the emotional one. Much of what rational thinking seems to do is rationalize one’s actions by fitting some logic to them.

In that sense the description coming out of journalism is certainly not just an unrealistic representation of the world but rather the one that can fool you the most by grabbing your attention via your emotional apparatus - the cheapest to deliver sensation. This sensationalism can divert empathy towards wrong causes.  Malnutrition in Africa and Southeast Asia no longer causes the emotional impact- so it literally dropped out of the picture.

The discussions in the media of the “terrorist threats” magnified the effect of these market moves in people’s heads. This is one of the many reasons that journalism may be the greatest plague we face today.

From the standpoint of an institution, the existence of a risk manager has less to do with actual risk reduction than it has to do with the impression of risk reduction.

Things are always obvious after the fact. When you look at the past the past will always be deterministic since only one single observation took place. Our minds are not quite designed to understand how the world works, but rather to get out of trouble rapidly and have progeny. A mistake is not something to be determined after the fact, but in the light of the information until that point. A more vicious effect of such hindsight bias is that those who are very good at predicting the past will think of themselves as good at predicting the future, and will feel confident about their ability to do so.

Look at the dramatic changes that have been brought about by the arrival of new technologies, such as the automobile, the airplane, the telephone, and the personal computer. Middlebrow inference (inference stripped of probabilistic thinking) would lead one to believe that all new technologies and inventions would likewise revolutionize our lives. But the answer is not so obvious: here we only see and count the winners, to the exclusion of the losers. The opportunity cost of missing a “new new thing” like the airplane and the automobile is miniscule compared to the toxicity of all the garbage one has to go through to get to these jewels (assuming these have brought some improvement to our lives, which I frequently doubt).

People do not realize that the media is paid to get their attention.

Let us remember that economists are evaluated on how intelligent they sound , not on a scientific measure of their knowledge of reality.

The reason is that John was never skilled in the first place. He is one of those people who happened to be there when it all happened. He may have looked the part but there are plenty of people who look the part.

The economist Robert Lucas dealt a blow to econometrics by arguing that if people were rational then their rationality would cause them to figure out predictable patterns from the past and adapt so that past information would be completely useless for predicting the future.

No amount of observations of white swans can allow the inference that all swans are white, but the observation of a single black swan is sufficient to refute that conclusion.

There are only two types of theories:

1.    Theories that are known to be wrong, as they were tested and adequately rejected (falsified)

2.    Theories that have not yet been known to be wrong, not falsified yet, but are exposed to be proved wrong.

The simple notion of a good model for society that cannot be left open for falsification is totalitarian.

The major problem with inference in general is that those whose profession is to derive conclusions from data often fall into the trap faster and more confidently than others. The more data we have, the more likely we are to drown in it.

In real life one sees only the winners - it is natural for those who failed to vanish completely.

Here we have a woman who married an extremely successful man but all she can see is comparative failure, for she cannot emotionally compare him to a sample that would do him justice. You get rich, move to rich neighborhoods, then become poor again (social treadmill effect). 

Optimism, it is said, is predictive of success. Predictive? It can also be predictive of failure. Optimistic people certainly take more risks as they are over confident about the odds; those who win show up among the rich and famous, others fail and disappear from the analyses. Sadly.

Remember that nobody accepts randomness in his own success, but only in his failure.

Carl Sagan examined the cures from cancer that resulted from a visit to Lourdes in France, where people were healed by simple contact with the holy waters, and found out the interesting fact that of the total cancer patients who visited the place, the cure rate was, if anything, lower than the statistical one for spontaneous remissions. It was lower than the average for those who did not go to Lourdes!

Philosophers of statistics call this the reference case problem to explain that there is no true attainable randomness in practice, only in theory.

What has gone wrong with the development of economics as a science? There was a bunch of intelligent people who felt compelled to use mathematics just to tell themselves that they were rigorous in their thinking, that theirs was a science.

Buridan’s donkey: Imagine a donkey equally hungry and thirsty placed at equal distance from sources of food and water. In such a framework, he would die of both thirst and hunger as he would be unable to decide which one to get to first. The reader no doubt has played a version of Buridan’s donkey, by flipping a coin to break some of the minor stalemates in life where one lets randomness help with the decision process.

We can conjure up one and only one state at a given time, i.e. either 0 or $2000. Left to our own devices, we are likely to bet in an irrational way, as one of the states would dominate the picture – the fear of ending with nothing or the excitement of an extra $1000.

Rules have their value. We just follow them not because they are the best but because they are useful and they save time and effort.

Satisficing (melding together of satisfy and suffice) was the idea of Herbert Simon. We are rational but in a limited way: boundedly rational.

Since the Kahneman and Tversky results, an entire discipline called behavioral finance and economics has flourished.

Neurobiologists believe that we have three brains: a very old one, the reptilian brain that dictates heartbeat that we share with all animals; the limbic brain centre of emotions that we share with mammals; and the neocortex or cognitive brain that distinguishes primates and humans.

Damasio reported that the purely unemotional man was incapable of making the simplest decision. It seems that the emotions are the ones doing the job. Psychologists call them lubricants of reason.

Unless the source of the statement has extremely high qualifications, the statement will be more revealing of the author than the information intended by him. Wittgenstein’s ruler: Unless you have confidence in the ruler’s reliability, if you use a ruler to measure a table you may also be using the table to measure the ruler.

We are not made to view things as independent from each other. When viewing two events A and B, it is hard not to assume that A causes B, B causes A, or both cause each other. Our bias is immediately to establish a causal link.

It is emotionally harder to reject a hypothesis than to accept it.

The Greek philosopher Pyrrho, who advocated a life of equanimity and indifference, was criticized for failing to keep his composure during a critical circumstance (he was chased by an ox). His answer was that he found it sometimes difficult to rid himself of his humanity.

Most of us know pretty much how we should behave. It is the execution that is the problem, not the absence of knowledge.

Many people get married to their ideas all the way to the grave. Beliefs are said to be path dependent if the sequence of ideas is such that the first one dominates.

When French writer Henry de Montherlant was told that he was about to lose his eyesight to a degenerative disease, he found it most appropriate to take his own life. The stioc’s prescription was precisely to elect what one can do to control one’s destiny in front of a random outcome. At the end, one is allowed to choose between no life at all and what one is given by destiny; we always have an option against uncertainty.

Recall that epic heroes were judged by their actions and not by the results. No matter how sophisticated our choices, how good we are at dominating the odds, randomness will have the last word. We are left only with dignity as a solution – dignity defined as the execution of a protocol of behavior that doesn’t depend on the immediate circumstance. It may not the optimal one, but it certainly is the one that makes us feel best.

The poem “Apoleipein o Theos Antonion” (The God abandons Antony) by Greek poet Cavafy addresses Marc  Antony, who has just lost the battle against Octavius and was forsaken by Bacchus, the god who until then had protected him. It is a beautiful poem advising a man who had just received a crushing reversal of fortune (According to legend even his horse deserted him to go to his enemy Octavius). It asks him just to bid her farewell, Alexandria the city that is leaving him. It tells him not to mourn his luck, not to enter denial, not to believe that his ears and eyes are deceiving him. Antony, do not degrade yourself with false hopes.

The God Abandons Antony 

If unexpectedly, in middle night,

an unseen company be heard to pass,

with music and with voices exquisite, —

turn not away and uselessly lament

your fortune that is giving in, your work

that came to nothing, the projects of your life

that proved illusory from first to last.

As one prepared long since, as fits the brave,

bid now farewell to the departing city,

farewell to the Alexandria you love.

And above all, do not deceive yourself:

say not that your impression was a dream,

that, it may be, your hearing played you false:

to futile hopes like these never descend.

As one prepared long since, as fits the brave,

as most fits you who gained so great a city,

approach the open window steadily,

and with emotion, but without the plaints

and supplications of the timorous,

listen — knowing it to be your last delight —

listen to the elysian sounds, the exquisite

instruments of the mystic company;

and bid farewell to the city you are losing,

farewell to the Alexandria you love.

 

(Poems by C. P. Cavafy. Translated, from the Greek, by J. C. Cavafy. Ikaros, 2003)

No comments: